রবিবার, ১৪ এপ্রিল, ২০১৩

Permanent Settlement


Concluded by the Cornwallis administration in 1793, Permanent Settlement was a grand contract between the east india company government and the Bengal landholders (zamindars and independent talukdars of all denominations). Under the contract, the landholders or zamindars were admitted into the colonial state system as the absolute proprietors of landed property. Besides being turned into proprietors of land, the zamindars were endowed with the privilege of holding their proprietary right at a rate which was to continue unchanged for ever. Under the contract the government was barred from enhancing its revenue demand on the zamindars.
Though the zamindars had the right to transfer their land freely by way of sale, mortgage or gift, their raiyats were denied such a privilege. They had the customary right to hold the land hereditarily subject to payment of rent regularly, but no right at all to transfer the right in any form. In relation to government, zamindars had of course one obligation to perform. It was to pay the government revenue demand absolutely punctually. The zamindars were warned that in case any of them failed to pay the kist at the stipulated date "a sale (in auction) of the whole of the lands of the defaulter, or such portion of them as may be sufficient to make good the arrears, will positively and invariably take place." (Section 7, Regulation 1, 1793)
The permanent settlement, the outcome of a long drawn debate and discussion among the policymakers of the East India Company must not be looked at as merely an arrangement for revenue collection. It was rather contrived as the core part of the control system of the colonial state. All other parts of the administration, such as executive, judiciary, and police were geared to the desired working of the permanent settlement system. However, in spite of all care to preserve the system, it began to erode under the impact of new circumstances effected by the rise of imperialism and later, the growth of nationalism, introduction of the revenue sale law, and growth of population. The system suffered a series of amendments and modifications and finally, it was abolished in 1950.
The English East India Company was growing in political power ever since the foundation of Calcutta zamindari (1698). Even though the company became the most dominant power after the defeat of sirajuddaula at the battle of palashi (1757) the process of its becoming the actual ruler of the country began, in fact, from the assumption of diwani of Bengal, Bihar and Orissa (1765) which turned the company into being the virtual 'king' of Bengal.
But due to many constraints, the new 'king' was not in a position to rule the kingdom directly from the start. As merchants and mercantile accountants the company officials in Bengal might have been adept in buying and selling of goods and in drawing long business balance sheets but in the art of administration they were entirely novice. The factors like paucity of manpower, language, ignorance of the native institutions and presence of other rival maritime nations in Bengal were compelling enough to prompt the company to go slow in building the colonial state.
At the very initial stage, the company chose to rule the nascent state with the help of its native collaborators. The problem for the rookie rulers was that Bengal was not a settled colony like America and Australia that it would be governed according to the laws and institutions of the motherland. Nor was it a savage society like those of Africa and the Pacific that it would be kept under control by lashes. Bengal's record of civilization was as old as England's, if not older. What was worse, the company was not in a position to rule BengalBengal's own laws and institutions, because such a choice would be contrary to the main purpose of founding the colonial state - using Bengal revenue for conducting its eastern trade. Under the circumstances the plan of according to robert clive, the hero of the Palashi episode and author of the Diwani Treaty (1765), was to allow the kingdom to be governed, for some time at least, by the native people according to their own laws and institutions and the company was only to oversee the native authority as the suprapower and receive the surplus revenue through a resident at the Nawab's darbar in murshidabad.
Syed Muhammed Reza Khan (1717?-1791), an adventurer from Iran and a long resident in Bengal as a land administrator, was entrusted with the responsibility of ruling the country of behalf of the company. He was appointed the naib or deputy diwan and naib nazim or deputy of the minor nawab (Najm-ud-daula) of Bengal. As naib nazim he was the chief of nizamat or civil administration and as naib diwan he was the chief of diwani or revenue administration. Reza Khan was allowed to rule according to native laws and institutions.
The Clive system, generally called dual or double government in the textbook, worked well until 1767, the year of the final departure of Clive from Bengal. Supported by Clive, Reza Khan was able to rule the company's kingdom efficiently. But with the departure of his patron, Reza Khan's authority confronted challenges from the ambitious Fort William officials who, being eager to accumulate wealth overnight, were determined to curtail his influence and in phases take over the administration into their own hands. The first visible sign of their interference was the appointment of European supervisors to various districts apparently with the responsibility of 'inquiring into the history of the provinces', but practically, they behaved like predators in the countryside, as the Khan often complained.
The next step towards the direct governance was the establishment of two revenue councils at Murshidabad (for Bengal) and Patna (for Bihar and Orissa). The supervisors worked under these two councils. Reza Khan had been constantly complaining to the Fort William council that in the name of inland trade and commerce the company officials were ravaging the countryside, but his complaints only irked the Fort WilliamBengal. Two-thirds of Bengal's productive land went into the state of nature due to lack of cultivating manpower. This holocaust had changed the whole previous thinking of the rulers about the mode of administration of the new kingdom. The idea of administering the company's diwani by native agency was abandoned. Under the orders of the court of directors (28 August 1771), the Calcutta Fort William council made itself the supreme government of the suba as regards diwani administration. Naib Diwan Reza Khan was dismissed and jailed for 'corruption and irregularities'. authorities. The consequence was the rapid decline of agriculture and manufactures and finally, the great famine of 1769-70, which destroyed one third of the total population of
To administer the company's territorial affairs a central authority called Committee of Revenue was instituted at Calcutta (1772) with the governor and president of the Fort William in Bengal as its president thus inaugurating quietly the capital city of the British empire. warren hastings, the Fort William governor, asserted that with the abolition of the Clive system, the diwani and nizamat administrations stood united as before 1765. Based on this interpretation a series of promulgation was issued in 1772. According to these promulgation the lands were to be leased out to revenue farmers for five years through public auction. A committee of circuit headed by the governor and four members of the council would be in charge of forming quinquennial settlement and collecting revenue from ijaradars (leaseholders); and all native district officers styled as faujdars, kanungos and amils were to be replaced by the British collectors.
In its consequences, the quinquennial revenue settlement proved to be disastrous. The revenue farmers, who came in land control form various professions for higher income, in general practiced rack renting. Raiyats responded to such predatory development by desertions, arjis (petition to authorities), combinations and even uprisings in many places. As the government itself was committed to collecting higher and higher revenue and, as it had neither the moral strength nor administrative ability to relieve the oppressed raiyats, the economic conditions in the countryside were deteriorating fast. The balances of revenue unrealised were increasing progressively ever since the conclusion of the settlement. However, it became very clear to government that the five-year settlement was a colossal mistake. The government realised also that the hereditary zamindars had a social stake in land control which the temporary ijaradars lacked. It was felt that the restoration of zamindars to their old status and assessment of revenue according to resources of estates would stabilise the revenue collections on the one hand and relieve the peasantry of ijaradari oppression on the other. But the government was bound by the terms of settlement for five years.
Until then the only option for the government was to consider and conceive in advance what might be the best mode of revenue collection on the expiry of the ruinous farming system in 1777. Thus a number of alternative suggestions were advanced. In a minute recorded on 28 March 1775, Richard Barwell, a member of the council, recommended for a settlement with the zamindars for a long term, one or two generations at least. On 22 January 1776, Philip Francis, another council member, had advanced his thesis in a lengthy minute which he called a Plan of Permanent Settlement of the Revenues, 1776. According to him land belonged to zamindars and it must be settled with them in perpetuity. Warren Hastings was in agreement with both Barwell and Francis as regards settlement with zamindars, but he insisted for ascertaining in detail the resources of the country before the tenure of settlement was fixed. On these views, the court of directors gave its own ruling which was very close to the views of Hastings. On 24 December 1776, on the eve of the expiry of five-year settlement, the court directed that the practice of leasing out land in auction be abandoned for a short-term settlement with zamindars alone. The court also advised the council to conduct necessary survey to ascertain accurately the resources of land with a view to making a durable settlement. The council thus resolved to make settlement with zamindars on annual basis for 1777 and three succeeding years.
But the new system could not arrest the declining trend of revenue collection. Revenue arrears continued to accumulate. Attempts were made to reverse the trend by decentralising the administration in 1786 by making the district collector the sole representative of the state. In order to make the colonial district collector, (in power comparable only to Mughal faujdars of olden days), was placed in a position of trust. In him was combined all executive and judicial powers. He could not make land settlement directly and single handedly without taking prior sanction from the Committee of Revenue. The committee, the symbol or centralisation and interference, was abolished and replaced by a new body, the board of revenue charged with general control of revenue affairs. To the collector the landholders had to look for a just assessment of revenue, and to him, the Board of Revenue had to look for the revenue of the state. The reforms of 1786 truly laid the administrative foundation of the permanent settlement. Structurally, the government was now prepared to deal with the landholders more confidently and firmly than ever before. But such preparedness does not mean greater regularity in revenue collection which continued to remain uncertain.
The pitt's india act of 1784 had a clause directing the Calcutta government to stop revenue experiments forthwith and make a permanent settlement of land revenue with the zaimindars under terms and conditions beneficial to both the parties - government and zamindars. lord cornwallis, a member of the British landlord class, was sent in 1786 with positive instructions to conclude the settlement. In charting his policy priorities, Lord Cornwallis, on his arrival, made the revenue settlement his first job. But in implementing his task he faced strong opposition from his own chief revenue advisor, John Shore (President of the Board of Revenue and Member of the Council), recognised to be the greatest land revenue specialist on Bengal. Shore believed that there was not enough information with the government to conclude a permanent settlement immediately. He was not against the idea of permanent settlement in principle. His objection was to the timing of making the settlement. Shore argued how a permanent settlement might harm all parties permanently including the government if it is made without consideration to actual resources of individual estates and also to the actual rights and obligations of various interests in land including raiyats. Shore was in favour of deferring the permanent settlement for another two or three decades so that enough information could be gathered in the meantime about land resources and land rights.
On the question of further inquiry into the resources of the country before permanent settlement, Cornwallis differed with Shore very drastically. He argued that whatever information had been gathered during the last twenty years was enough for concluding permanent settlement. He further argued that if any discrepancy occurred to any individual party or parties, it would soon be adjusted under the impact of the permanent settlement. Cornwallis believed that the permanent settlement would instill enough impetus to landholders to turn themselves into landlords and agrarian capitalists.
However, Cornwallis and Shore agreed to send their respective views and other related documents to the court of directors for a final decision about the issue. They also agreed that in the meantime the government should form a settlement for a term of ten years from 1790 with a notice to the landholders that if the court of directors gave direction in favour of permanent settlement, the decennial settlement would be declared permanent immediately. The court of directors, after studying all the minutes from all members of the council, gave its opinion in favour of permanent settlement. On 23 March 1793, Lord Cornwallis proclaimed that "at the expiration of the terms of the (decennial) settlement, no alteration would be made in the assessment which (zamidnars had) respectively engaged to pay, but that they, and their heirs and lawful successors, would be allowed to hold their estates at such assessment for ever" (Proclamation Article III, Section 4, Regulation 1, 1793).
Zamindars' responses The Cornwallis administration expected, possibly with valid grounds, that the new system would be enthusiastically received by the zamindars as an unprecedented privilege, for it had created private property in land which never existed before and that the newly created landed property was vested in the zamindars free of cost. Most importantly, zamindars got the very unique privilege of paying government revenue at a fixed rate forever, a decision which was certainly a sacrifice for government in fiscal terms. Obviously, the government thought that the zamindars, as great beneficiaries, would respond to the settlement enthusiastically and with thanks and gratitude to the good governance of the British. But to the utter dismay of the government, the zamindars were seen to have expressed dissatisfaction and disgust to the permanent settlement. Many disgruntled zamindars even went to the extent of rejecting the settlement and some offered open resistance.
There were many valid reasons why the zamindars were not happy about the terms of the permanent settlement. The revenue assessment on individual zamindars was made on a crude estimation based on the average actual collection of rents for the preceding ten years. Such an unsound method of assessment could lead to very small incidence of revenue demand on some, and very heavy on others. The heavily assessed estates were bound to fall in chronic revenue arrears and consequently be exposed to public sale and annihilation.
The government's firm declaration that no remission of revenue would be allowed in the future "on account of drought, inundation, encroachments and depredation of rivers, death or flight of raiyats" was looked at by zamindars as utterly unrealistic. To them, the most impractical condition imposed was the punctual payment of revenue failing which the lands of the zamindars were to be sold in public auction for realising the arrears. In an agrarian economy based on erratic monsoon rains, occasional crop failures and consequently revenue arrears were inevitable. They argued forcefully that if the authorities were unable to make monsoon rains occur absolutely regularly and punctually then how could they insist on land revenue payers to pay their dues absolutely regularly and punctually?
The concerned zamindars, while arguing with the settlement people, invoked the great tradition under which landholders always got moukuf (remission) of public revenue whenever crops failed due to natural causes. Rasad (progressive increase) of revenue for three years from 1790 was another cause of complaint on the part of the zamindars. The rasad policy was treated by zamindars as highly arbitrary and unacceptable, because the increase was based on pre-supposition that the resources of the estates would increase. Such an assumption was highly presumptuous and irrational.
Another area of zamindar's complaint was the taluk policy. Under the rules of the permanent settlement all taluks hitherto paying revenue through the zamindars were to be separated from them and treat such separated estates as independent zamindaris. All large zamindaris had numerous such taluks under their control and these were separated from them without compensation. Consequent upon the separation of taluks many zamindaris, which had hitherto created taluks for management or other reasons, were reduced in size and many of them even got extinct practically. For zamindars, another irritating law was the so-called patta Regulation (Regulation VIII 1793) which required the zamindars to issue pattas to raiyats stating terms and conditions of bandobast (settlement) and strictly prohibiting them from collecting any abwab or imposition over and above the stipulated amount of rent. The zamindars looked at it as a naked encroachment into what was claimed to be the internal affairs of the zamindari management and control.
The general unrest and commotion among zamindars, large-scale transfer of lands under the operation of the revenue sale law, declining trend of government revenue, failure of the judiciary to clear up the mounting piles of revenue suits, deteriorating law and order situation, and all other accompanying factors, were disquieting enough for the government. It was strongly felt that the trend must be reversed before the development went beyond control. The authorities could content themselves that though the rules of the permanent settlement had considerably disturbed the traditional social and economic structures of the old landed aristocracy, the new regime had conversely been able to attract support from assorted social elements, such as, emancipated talukdars, jotedars, lightly assessed landholders, new landlords, emergent banians, Anglo-Indian mercantile interests and so on. But socially, they were not yet respectable and powerful enough to lead the society in favour of the government at times of a crisis.
The administration of Lord Wellesley (1797-1805), which was committed to empire building, noticed the post-permanent settlement development with grave concern. Hundreds of zamindaris were put to auction sales every month; government's revenue collection became as irregular and uncertain as before 1793; the administrative cost rose; revenue income declined; law and order in the country deteriorated. The dismembered zamindars, shorn of their zamindaris and princely image, more often than not put up quite effective resistance to successful bidders who came to take possession of their lots purchased at auctions.
Such a scene cannot comfort a government at war and a home government looking forward to a regular flow of remittance after the new system. Wellesley resolved to conciliate the zamindar class by bringing some amendments to the basic rules of the permanent settlement. The result was the enactment of Regulation VII of 1799, commonly known as haftam or seventh, which armed the zamindars with despotic powers over their defaulting raiyats. The zamindars could now distrait their crops, cattle and other properties and sell them, in the name of recovering arrears, without any judicial intermediation. They, as absolute proprietors, could summon the defaulting raiyats to their katcharis and keep them confined in fetters until the arrears were paid. They could impose community fines on the whole village if any of the defaulting raiyats ran away to safety with his family and property. They could enhance rent without any regard to pargana customs and usages. In short, the haftam had negated all customary rights that the raiyats had been enjoying traditionally and reduced them to mere tenants-at-will.
The next change in the original law of permanent settlement was the Regulation V of 1812 (popularly know as panjam or fifth) under which the zamindars got the right to lease out their land for any period. Originally, the lease period was kept limited to a maximum term of ten years. However, the amendment, which had fundamentally changed the character of permanent settlement was the Regulation VIII of 1819, which came down in the Bengal agrarian history as the pattani law.
This law empowered the zamindars to create perpetual intermediary rights in land between themselves and actual cultivators. In other words, the pattani law authorised the zamindars to create 'little permanent settlements' under themselves as they were under the government. This was, indeed, the height of the growth of zamindari powers and, at the same time, the depth of the Cornwallisian spirit or the permanent settlement. Under this law, the zamindars could sell the land of the defaulting pattanidars in public auction, in the same manner as the land of the defaulting zamindars was being sold now under the Sunset Law.
Objectives and effects of Permanent Settlement The conclusion of the permanent settlement with zamindars had some immediate objectives in view. These may be classified as: (a) placing revenue paying on a definite footing and making revenue collection sure and certain; (b) ensuring a minimum revenue; (c) relieving officials of revenue matter and engaging them to other spheres of administration; and finally, (d) forging an alliance between the zamindar class and the colonial rulers. Though not entirely but largely, government succeeded in achieving these short-term goals. The revenue paying agency was put on a definite footing in the person of zamindar. The government now knew how much was to be its annual inflow from land and the zamindars also knew for certain their contractual obligation to government. Formerly, neither the government nor the revenue payers knew exactly where did they stand as regards revenue collection and payment.
The revenue law worked as a successful mechanism for maintaining a minimum revenue collection which was hard to imagine in the earlier period. Forging an alliance with the zamindar for political purpose was not achieved immediately, because the original terms of the settlement did not satisfy them, But over time, when zamindari powers were made unlimited and when government revenue demand became lighter through rise in prices and inflation, the landlord class did cooperate with the government. Their solidarity with the government during the sepoy revolt and Swadeshi and militant nationalist movements in the early twentieth century vindicates it.
But the permanent settlement had nobler long-term objects, which were made plain in the various council minutes and correspondence on the eve of its enactment. Its authors anticipated that the operation of the new system, which was thought to have been devised with some in-built mechanism for social and economic transformation, would first bring about capitalist changes in agriculture and agrarian relations, and eventually trigger off an industrial revolution in the country. It was expected that the proprietary right in land and fixity of government revenue demand for all time to come would induce zamindars to turn themselves into progressive landlords like their counterparts in Britain. The profit motive would drive them to invest their surplus capital in various sectors of agriculture, such as abad or reclamation of land under forest, irrigation, drainage, communication, agricultural credit, improved seed, hats and bazaars, fisheries, livestock, and so on. The expectation was that changes in agriculture would, in turn, lead to transformation in trade, commerce and industries and the cumulative changes would lead to ever increasing income for the government in the form of tariff and taxes. Such a development, it was thought, would well compensate for the loss that the government had deliberately incurred in the long term by fixing the government revenue on zamindars in perpetuity.
Unfortunately, the long-term vision behind the permanent settlement did not materialise. The zamindars, old or new, never turned themselves into landlords like their British counterparts. There is no difference of opinion among scholars as to zamindars' failure in changing the country, but they differ drastically as to why the zamindars behaved the way they did. Instead of improving land by means of capital and organisational input, their strategy was to increase income by other more profitable means such as mahajani investment, grain trade, purchase of new estates, bonds, urban properties, and enhancing rent and imposing abwabs or illegal cesses on raiyats. Viewed economically, such behaviour on the part of zamindars was justified on the ground that the sectors where they invested their surpluses had been yielding much higher returns than land management on capitalist line. If investment in land was less profitable and more risky, then why should the zamindars sink capital in land if they were rational? In England, there was a strong industrial sector to stimulate agriculture, and there were government moves to stabilise prices and safeguard the interests of the landed classes; but under the colonial situation in Bengal, zamindars were deprived of such benefits.
A certain amount of industrialisation is a prerequisite for agricultural growth. Bengal agricultural economy lost that advantage under the company rule when the great manufacturing tradition of Bengal collapsed. The agricultural sector under British rule was never free from adverse factors such as recurring famines and scarcities, fluctuating prices, colonial deindustrialisation and drainage of wealth. Such an environment was not congenial to the growth of capitalist outlook but to the consumptive feudal mind, which the zamindar class had truly demonstrated.
The most remarkable trail of feudal values that the zamindars had acquired from the permanent settlement was living on unearned income. They transferred the zamindari management and control to a permanent intermediate class in exchange for an annuity. In other words, as the absolute proprietors of land they made, tenurially a second permanent settlement with the lease-holders under more or less the same terms and conditions as their own settlement with the government. They received the annuity from the perpetual tenureholders by virtue of their right in land, not by any claim to capital investment in it. Their rights and liabilities in relation to zamindars were practically the same as the zamindari rights and liabilities in relation to government. Consequently, the tenureholders also created, in turn, sub-tenures, and the process of gradation sometimes went down several steps, in Bakerganj for example, to as many as fifteen steps.
The problem of the rise of hierarchic intermediate classes in land control had, indeed, deep economic and social implications. The revenue survey records (1860-1870) and records of survey and settlement operations (1886 onwards) reveal that the zamindars who had created intermediate tenures in the wake of the permanent settlement were mostly saved from the operation of the 'sunset law' and that the rent burden on raiyats was the heaviest in those estates where the chain of intermediate tenures was the highest. In other words, there is a correlation between the stability of zamindari rights and intermediate tenures on the one hand, and the high rate of rent and intermediate tenures, on the other. There is another important aspect of intermediate tenures. It is the role of the tenureholders in the extension of agriculture into hitherto jungle land. The clearing of extensive tracts of land in various parts of Bengal, particularly the coastal zones, in the nineteenth century was the feat of mainly the intermediate classes. It is they who led the reclamation with their capital, organisation and manpower. The productive role of the intermediate classes, however, stopped in the beginning of the 20th century when no more vacant land was left for clearing, and with that the tenureholders, excepting the tier just above the raiyats, were left with no role to play in the land management and thus were turned into parasites living on peasant production.
The erosion of Permanent Settlement The crisis of the zamindari power and control that is noted immediately after the system was put to operation was soon followed by a spell of stability, and even of relative prosperity of the zamindar class. The summary powers provided by a series of enactments (Regulation XXXV of 1795, Regulation VII of 1799, Regulation V of 1812 and Regulation VIII of 1819) enabled the zamindars to enhance rent and collect it expeditiously. The public sale of zamindari land due to revenue arrears thus became a rare phenomenon from 1820. The opening of the country to free trade from 1813 led to an ever larger volume of export of primary products with its positive effects on zamindari income. Population growth and consequent extension of agriculture, introduction of commercial crops and rising trend in prices had their happy effects on the zamindari economy.
Unfortunately, the prosperity of the zamindar class did not lead to a corresponding prosperity of the peasantry (raiyats). The peasant surpluses were systematically extracted by the zamindars and intermediate interests in the form of enhanced rent and myriad impositions, such as, abwabs, tuhuri, dasturi, chandas, bhet, nazrana, begar, selami, etc. Peasants continued to produce subsistence plus rent only. With the integration of the country with the global capitalist economy from the early nineteenth century, the subsistence economy in the rural society came under severe strains. A series of peasant uprisings in most parts of Bengal, especially in eastern Bengal, from the late 1850s was the most direct manifestation of the estranged relationship between the zamindars and raiyats. The crisis was triggered off by the peasant disturbances in the Santal Pargana first (1855) and then in the indigo districts (1859-61). The indigo resistance movement continued from 1858 to 1860.
The peasant resistance movements took an alarming turn in the 1870s and early 1880s when the peasants in several parts of eastern Bengal made jotes (alliances) among themselves to assert their rights in land and minimise extraction of surpluses by zamindars. The most remarkable of the peasant uprisings in this period were the Tushkhali (in Bakerganj) peasant movement (1872-75), pabna peasant uprising (1873), chhagalnaiya (Noakhali) peasant movement (1874), mymensingh tribal peasant movement (1874-1882), munshiganj (Dhaka) peasant movement (1880-81) and mehendiganj (Bakerganj) uprising (1880-81). The Faraizis (a Muslim reformist sect) took up the peasants' cause and the faraizi movement established extensive network across the country, particularly in south Bengal, against the zamindari control. A common demand of all these peasant jotes was the restoration of raiyati rights in land.
These uprisings indicate for certain the gradual erosion of the permanent settlement. The proprietary classes had lost their grips on the raiyats who were now asserting their rights in land. Zamindars, being unable to contain the rebellious raiyats, asked for government help to discipline the recalcitrant raiyats and government did send police, and even armed forces where necessary, to quell the disturbances. Most government reports on the peasant movements pointed to the weakening state of the zamindar class, particularly to its impoverished conditions. The operation of the law of inheritance and consequent partition and re-partition of estates, family feuds, litigation, absenteeism, creation of intermediate tenures, untimely death of proprietors, extravagance, and many other associated factors had eroded the zamindar class structurally. On the other side, an affluent and assertive agrarian middle class in the persons of madhyasvatvas or intermediate tenureholders, jotedars, hawladars and other rich peasants was emerging steadily since the first quarter of the nineteenth century.
Rent Act 1859 No longer the government, as the events developed, could ignore the peasantry, particularly its rich section, as an interest in land. The Sepoy Revolt and the closely followed indigo disturbances awakened the government to the dangers of further ignoring the rural cause. Saving the loyal zamindar class was an imperial need and saving the protesting peasantry was at the same time a political dictate.
An outcome of this perception was the enactment of Rent Act in 1859, which tried to recognise the rights of some categories of raiyats. Instead of traditional classification of raiyats into khudkast and paikast, the peasant society was now categorised into three legal groups under the Rent Act. These are: (a) raiyats holding land at a fixed rate of rent from the time of the permanent settlement; (b) raiyats having a right of occupancy, ie raiyats holding continuously land for twelve years; and (c) raiyats not having a right of occupancy, ie raiyats holding land for less than twelve years. To secure the rights of raiyats and to regulate the payment of their rent patta system was reintroduced. From now on, the payment of rent was to be regulated by the terms of the patta which specified the amount of annual rent (cash or kind), and beyond which zamindars would have no right to impose any abwab which was now made a punishable offense (section 2).
The zamindars lost the power vested in them by haftam (Reg. VII 1799) of compelling any category of raiyats to report to kachari and adjust arrears or undergo physical torture in default (section 11). The Rent Act had barred the zamindars from enhancing the first category of raiyats (kayemi) whose rent was fixed permanently and they also lost power to enhance the rent of occupancy raiyats without showing reasons like zamindari investment, rise in prices, etc. The rent of non-occupancy raiyats could not be enhanced too frequently.
The zamindars, by now too dependent on government support, did not have the guts to oppose the Rent Act. Instead they just tried to ignore it. They knew it well that enacting a law was something and implementing it was something else. They kept on enhancing rent as before. The defaulting raiyats were still called to kachari and tortured for adjustment of arrears. Occupancy right was usually denied. As a result, the landlord-tenant relations deteriorated progressively the extent of which can be measured from the large scale peasant discontents in the 1870s and early 1880s.
Bengal Tenancy Act 1885 The mounting peasant unrest in the 1870s was alarming enough for the government both economically and politically. The seething masses, according to reports of some district collectors, might someday storm the zamindari kacharis and finally the collectorate kacharis unless some positive measures were taken to soothe their rebellious mood. A rent commission was set up in 1879 to investigate the tense landlord-tenant relations and make remedial recommendations to government. From the report of the rent commission originated the bengal tenancy act of 1885 (Act VIII). The act for the first time tried to define the rights of various interests in land from the highest proprietor to the lowest cultivating raiyat. Indeed, the act considerably curtailed zamindari power and privileges.
No doubt, the Bengal Tenancy Act very considerably changed the original framework of the permanent settlement. A zamindar was now just one of the interests in land, a superior one, of course. What is more important, this time government did mean to implement the act. The operation of the Bengal Tenancy Act was closely monitored and it was found that law had very successfully established peace in the countryside.
But peasant agitation began again in the 1920s. One effect of the electoral politics under the constitution of 1919 was the need for mass contact for success in polls. Necessity had impelled all major political parties to establish peasant wings of their respective parties, which tried to raise awareness about the agrarian problems besetting them. Prajas or raiyats, now made militantly conscious by the left activists, could feel that they were still deprived of the privileges of cutting trees, mortgaging land beyond a certain time, transferring lands without permission of landholders, building pucca structures and digging tanks and ponds. For all these zamindari sanctions were required and no sanction was accorded without a selami. Most of these limitations were removed by the Amendment Act of 1928. Under this act the raiyats got the rights to transfer lands without permission of landholders but they were still subject to pay salami and landlord's had still the right to preemption. They also got the right to cut trees and dig tanks and ponds and construct pucca structures without taking zamindari permission.
The end of Permanent Settlement With the enactment and implementation of the India Act of 1935 the peasant politics had received a fresh stimulus. Peasant grievances were articulated by the political parties. A new political organisation, krishak praja party (KPP), was formed in Bengal with the avowed objects of serving the interests of the praja class mainly and its leader Sher-e-Bangla ak fazlul huq, who politically committed himself to abolishing the permanent settlement if voted to power, had actually formed the government in 1937. Soon after, the Huq ministry formed a committee called Land Revenue Commission (generally known as floud commission after the name of its chairman Francis Floud) with specific terms of reference concerning the end of the permanent settlement. However, instead of waiting for the recommendations from the Land Revenue Commission the Huq ministry, in order to provide minimum satisfaction to his constituency, brought another amendment to the Bengal Tenancy Act in 1938 (Act VI) under which salami system and zamindar's right to preemption in the transfer of raiyati land were abolished and some rights of bargadars (sharecroppers) were recognised. Act VI of 1938 made the prajas virtual proprietors of land.
The Floud Commission, which submitted its report in 1940, found the zamindari system untenable under the changed circumstances and recommended for its immediate abolition including all intermediate rent receiving interests. But by then Huq, the advocate of praja cause, had become politically too effete to accomplish the task and thus the Floud Commission report remained unimplemented.
The incidents of the Tebhaga agitation in north Bengal (1946-47) served as a reminder to the government that the depressed peasantry was more for land reforms than for nationalist or communal politics. In response to the widespread tebhaga movement, the Bengal government headed by huseyn shaheed suhrawardy brought two bills for enactment - the State Acquisition and Tenancy Bill and the Bengal Bargadar (Provisional) Bill in early 1947. The intention was to abolish the permanent settlement and to improve the status of the sharecropping tenants. In view of the politics of partition, the two bills could not be finally enacted into law. However, after partition the bills were placed in the East Bengal Legislative Assembly in the form of a new bill called the East Bengal State Acquisition and Tenancy Bill, 1950. On 16 December 1950, the bill became on act entitled east bengal state acquisition and tenancy act 1950. Under the act the permanent settlement was at last abolished. The raiyats, now called maliks or proprietors of land, became direct tenants under the government.

Six-point Programme

A charter of demands enunciated by the awami league for removing disparity between the two wings of Pakistan and bring to an end the internal colonial rule of West Pakistan in East Bengal. The Indo-Pak War of 1965 ended with the execution of Taskent Treaty. To the old grievances of economic disparity added the complain of negligence and indifference of central government towards the defence of East Pakistan. Bangabandhu sheikh mujibur rahman was vocal on this issue.
The leaders of the opposition parties of West Pakistan convened a national convention at Lahore on 6 February 1966 with a view to ascertain the post-Taskent political trend. Bangabandhu reached Lahore on 4 February along with the top leaders of Awami League, and the day following he placed the Six-point Charter of demand before the subject committee as the demands of the people of East Pakistan. He created pressure to include his proposal in the agenda of the conference. They rejected the proposal of Bangabandhu. On the following day the newspapers of West Pakistan published reports on the Six-point programme, and Sheikh Mujibur Rahman was projected as a separatist. Consequently Sheikh Mujib abandoned the conference.
The Six-point programme along with a proposal of movement for the realisation of the demands was placed before the meeting of the working committee of Awami League on 21 February 1966, and the proposal was carried out unanimously. A booklet on the Six-point Programme with introduction from Bangabandhu Sheikh Mujib and Tajuddin Ahmad was published. Another booklet entitled 'Amader Banchar Dabi : 6-dafa Karmasuchi' (Our demands for existence : 6-points Programme) was published in the name of Sheikh Mujibur Rahman, and was distributed in the council meeting of Awami League held on 18 March 1966.  

Six points
1.
The constitution should provide for a Federation of Pakistan in its true sense on the Lahore Resolution and the parliamentary form of government with supremacy of a Legislature directly elected on the basis of universal adult franchise.
2.
The federal government should deal with only two subjects : Defence and Foreign Affairs, and all other residuary subjects shall be vested in the federating states.
3.
Two separate, but freely convertible currencies for two wings should be introduced ; or if this is not feasible, there should be one currency for the whole country, but effective constitutional provisions should be introduced to stop the flight of capital from East to West Pakistan. Furthermore, a separate Banking Reserve should be established and separate fiscal and monetary policy be adopted for East Pakistan.
4.
The power of taxation and revenue collection shall be vested in the federating units and the federal centre will have no such power. The federation will be entitled to a share in the state taxes to meet its expenditures.
5.
There should be two separate accounts for the foreign exchange earnings of the two wings ; the foreign exchange requirements of the federal government should be met by the two wings equally or in a ratio to be fixed; indigenous products should move free of duty between the two wings, and the constitution should empower the units to establish trade links with foreign countries.
6.
East Pakistan should have a separate militia or paramilitary force.

The opposition leaders of West Pakistan looked at Mujib's Six-point Programme as a device to disband Pakistan, and hence they outright rejected his proposal. The Ayub government arrested him and put him on trial what is known as agartala conspiracy case. The case led to widespread agitation in East Pakistan22 February 1969. culminating in the mass uprising of early 1969. Under public pressure, government was forced to release him unconditionally on
The Awami League sought public mandate in favour of the six point programme in the general elections of 1970 in which Mujib received the absolute mandate from the people of East Pakistan in favour of his six point. But Zulfiqar Ali Bhuttu refused to join the session of the National Assembly scheduled to be held on 3 March 1971 unless a settlement was reached between the two leaders beforehand. Sheikh Mujibur Rahman and his party sat in a protracted dialogue from 15 March 1971. The dialogue failed to produce any positive result. The army crackdown of 25 March sealed the fate of the six point including the fate of Pakistan.

Language Movement


Began in 1948 and reached its climax in the killing of 21 February 1952, and ended in the adoption of Bangla as one of the state languages of Pakistan. The question as to what would be the state language of Pakistan was raised immediately after its creation. The central leaders and the Urdu-speaking intellectuals of Pakistan declared that urdu would be the state language of Pakistan, just as Hindi was the state language of India. The students and intellectuals of East Pakistan, however, demanded that Bangla be made one of the state languages. After a lot of controversy over the language issue, the final demand from East Pakistan was that Bangla must be the official language and the medium of instruction in East Pakistan and for the central government it would be one of the state languages along with Urdu. The first movement on this issue was mobilised by Tamaddun Majlish headed by Professor Abul Kashem. Gradually many other non-communal and progressive organisations joined the movement, which finally turned into a mass movement.
Meanwhile, serious preparation was being taken in various forums of the central government of Pakistan under the initiative of Fazlur Rahman, the central education minister, to make Urdu the only state language of Pakistan. On receipt of this information, East Pakistani students became agitated and held a meeting on the Dhaka University campus on 6 December 1947, demanding that Bangla be made one of the state languages of Pakistan. The meeting was followed by student processions and more agitation. The first Rastrabhasa Sangram Parishad (Language Action Committee) was formed towards the end of December with Professor Nurul Huq Bhuiyan of Tamaddun Majlish as the convener.
The Constituent Assembly of Pakistan was in session at Karachi-then the capital of Pakistan-from 23 February 1948. It was proposed that the members would have to speak either in Urdu or in English at the Assembly. dhirendranath datta, a member from the East Pakistan Congress Party, moved an amendment motion to include Bangla as one of the languages of the Constituent Assembly. He noted that out of the 6 crore 90 lakh population of Pakistan, 4 crore 40 lakh were from East Pakistan with Bangla as their mother tongue. The central leaders, including liaquat ali khan, prime minister of Pakistan, and khwaja nazimuddin, chief minister of East Bengal, opposed the motion. On receiving the news that the motion had been rejected, students, intellectuals and politicians of East Pakistan became agitated. Newspapers such as the Azad also criticised of the politicians who had rejected the motion.
A new committee to fight for Bangla as the state language was formed with Shamsul Huq as convener. On 11 March 1948 a general strike was observed in the towns of East Pakistan in protest against the omission of Bangla from the languages of the Constituent Assembly, the absence of Bangla letters in Pakistani coins and stamps, and the use of only Urdu in recruitment tests for the navy. The movement also reiterated the earlier demand that Bangla be declared one of the state languages of Pakistan and the official language of East Pakistan. Amidst processions, picketing and slogans, leaders such as Shawkat Ali, Kazi Golam Mahboob, Shamsul Huq, Oli Ahad, sheikh mujibur rahman, Abdul Wahed and others were arrested. Student leaders, including Abdul Matin and abdul malek ukil, also took part in the procession and picketing. A meeting was held on the Dhaka University premises. Mohammad Toaha was severely injured while trying to snatch away a rifle from a policeman and had to be admitted to hospital. Strikes were observed from 12 March to 15 March.
Under such circumstances the government had to give in. Khwaja Nazimuddin signed an agreement with the student leaders. However, although he agreed to a few terms and conditions, he did not comply with their demand that Bangla be made a state language. muhammed ali jinnah, the governor general of Pakistan, came to visit East Pakistan on 19 March. He addressed two meetings in Dhaka, in both of which he ignored the popular demand for Bangla. He reiterated that Urdu would be the only state language of Pakistan. This declaration was instantly protested with the Language Movement spreading throughout East Pakistan. The Dhaka University Language Action Committee was formed on 11 March 1950 with Abdul Matin as its convener.
By the beginning of 1952, the Language Movement took a serious turn. Both Jinnah and Liaquat Ali Khan were dead-Jinnah on 11 September 1948 and Liaquat Ali Khan on 16 October 1951. Khwaja Nazimuddin had succeeded Liaquat Ali Khan as prime minister of Pakistan. With the political crisis, the economic condition in East Pakistan also deteriorated. The people of East Pakistan started losing faith in the Muslim League. A new party, the Awami Muslim League-which would later become the awami league-was formed under the leadership of maulana abdul hamid khan bhasani in 1949. There was a growing sense of deprivation and exploitation in East Pakistan and a realisation that a new form of colonialism had replaced British imperialism. Under these circumstances, the Language Movement got a new momentum in 1952.
On 27 January 1952, Khwaja Nazimuddin came to Dhaka from Karachi. Addressing a meeting at Paltan Maidan, he said that the people of the province could decide what would be the provincial language, but only Urdu would be the state language of Pakistan. There was an instantaneous, negative reaction to this speech among the students who responded with the slogan, 'Rashtrabhasha Bangla Chai' (We want Bangla as the state language).
A strike was observed at Dhaka University on 30 January. The representatives of various political and cultural organisations held a meeting on 31 January chaired by Moulana Bhasani. An All-Party Central Language Action Committee was formed with Kazi Golam Mahboob as its convener. At this time the government also proposed that Bangla be written in Arabic script. This proposal was also vehemently opposed. The Language Action Committee decided to call a hartal and organise demonstrations and processions on February 21 throughout East Pakistan.
As preparations for demonstrations were underway, the government imposed Section 144 in the city of Dhaka, banning all assemblies and demonstrations. A meeting of the Central Language Action Committee was held on 20 February under the chairmanship of abul hashim. Opinion was divided as to whether or not to violate Section 144.
The students were determined to violate Section144 and held a student meeting at 11.00 a.m. on 21 February on the Dhaka University campus, then located close to the Medical College Hospital. When the meeting started, the Vice-Chancellor, along with a few university teachers, came to the spot and requested the students not to violate the ban on assembly. However, the students, under their leaders - Abdul Matin and Gaziul Huq - were adamant. Thousands of students from different schools and colleges of Dhaka assembled on the university campus while armed police waited outside the gate. When the students emerged in groups, shouting slogans, the police resorted to baton charge; even the female students were not spared.
The students then started throwing brickbats at the police, who retaliated with tear gas. Unable to control the agitated students, the police fired upon the crowd of students, who were proceeding towards the Assembly Hall (at present, part of Jagannath Hall, University of Dhaka). Three young men, rafiq uddin ahmed, abdul jabbar and abul barkat (an MA student of Political Science) were fatally wounded. Many injured persons were admitted to the hospital. Among them Abdus Salam, a peon at the Secretariat, subsequently succumbed to his wounds. A nine-year-old boy named Ohiullah was also killed.
At the Legislative Assembly building, the session was about to begin. Hearing the news of the shooting, some members of the Assembly, including maulana abdur rashid tarkabagish and some opposition members, went out and joined the students. In the Assembly, nurul amin, chief minister of East Pakistan, continued to oppose the demand for Bangla.
The next day, 22 February, was also a day of public demonstrations and police reprisals. The public performed a janaza (prayer service for the dead) and brought out a mourning procession, which was attacked by the police and the army resulting in several deaths, including that of a young man named Shafiur Rahman. Many were injured and arrested. On 23 February, at the spot where students had been killed, a memorial was erected. In 1963, the temporary structure was replaced by a concrete memorial, the shaheed minar (martyrs' memorial).
The East Bengal Legislative Assembly adopted a resolution recommending the recognition of Bangla as one of the state languages of Pakistan. The language movement continued until 1956. The movement achieved its goal by forcing the Pakistan Constituent Assembly in adopting both Bangla and Urdu as the state languages of Pakistan. While the Assembly was debating on the language issue, Member Adel Uddin Ahmed (1913-1981; Faridpur) made an important amendment proposal, which was adopted unanimously by the Assembly (16 February 1956). Both Bangla and Urdu were thus enacted to be the state languages of Pakistan.
Since 1952, 21 February has been observed every year to commemorate the martyrs of the Language Movement. With UNESCO adopting a resolution on 17 November 1999 proclaiming 21 February as international mother language day. It is an honour bestowed by the international community on the Language Movement of Bangladesh.

Gauda (Janapada)

An important geographical entity in ancient and medieval Bengal. The Arthashastra refers to it along with vanga, pundra and kamarupa. Though the geographical limit of the Gauda country is not mentioned, the fact that it is linked with Vanga and Pundra definitely indicates its location in eastern India. Vatsayana (3rd - 4th century AD) was familiar with this country. This geographical idea continues even in the Puranas as it is regarded as one of the janapadas of the eastern quarter. Varahamihira (c 6th century AD) was also aware of Gauda janapada. In his Brhat Sanghita he mentions six distinct janapadas viz: Gaudaka, Paundra, Vanga, samatata, Vardhamana and tamralipta. It appears from his narration that Murshidabad, Birbhum, and western Burdwan formed the territory of ancient Gauda.

The earliest epigraphic evidence referring to the territory of the Gauda people is the Haraha inscription of the Maukhari ruler Ishanavarman and is datable to 554 AD. It is stated in the inscription that Ishanavarman defeated the Gaudas who live near the sea (Gaudan samudrashrayan). This statement finds corroboration in the undated Gurgi inscription of Prabodhashiva (c 11th century AD) which describes the Lord of Gauda as 'lying in the watery fort of the sea' (jalanidhi jaladurggam Gauda rajo dhishete). The evidence of these two epigraphs drives home the fact that the Gaudas, at least at one point of history, lived in the coastal region.

With the passage of time and change in the political scenario the connotation of Gauda, however, underwent changes. The rise of shashanka, the ruler of Gauda, as a formidable power in the early part of the 7th century AD definitely led to the extension of the territorial limits of Gauda. From the accounts of hiuen-tsang we learn that he travelled from the country of karnasuvarna to a region in coastal Orissa, and the area was ruled by Shashanka. Obviously, the territory of Karnasuvarna stretched up to littoral West Bengal. Interestingly, this king Shashanka is described in Banabhatta's Harsacharita as the Lord of Gauda whose capital was at Karnasuvarna. In fact, Bana castigates him as Gauda bhujanga (the dangerous Gauda snake). Thus in the early part of the 7th century Gauda and Karnasuvarna were co-terminous. On the basis of Hiuen Tsang's itinerary and the archaeological remains of raktamrittika mahavihara, Karnasuvarna, the capital city of Gauda kingdom has been located near Chiruti in Murshidabad district of West Bengal. Hence Murshidabad formed the core area of Gauda.

The political limits of the geographical name Gauda further extended to the region of north Bengal, ie Pundravardhana. From the Aryamanjushri Mulakalpa we learn that Pundravardhana was ruled by Shashanka. This statement finds corroboration in the allusion to a struggle in the Dubi plates between Susthitavarman and Bhaskarvarman of Kamarupa on the one side and the king of Gauda on the other. As a ruler Bhaskarvarman's contemporary was Shashanka. The struggle might have taken place in north Bengal. We know from Hiuen Tsang that Pundravardhana and Kamarupa were contiguous territories. Thus Gauda under Shashanka embraced parts of west Bengal, including its coasts, and north Bengal (at least for a short time).

The appellation Gauda was applied even to areas outside Bengal. It was used in a political sense in the Gaudavaho of Vakpati. In Vakpati's account Magadha was included within the realm of the Gauda ruler.
In the early medieval period, the term Gauda had a wider connotation. The Rastrakuta and the Pratihara records styled the Pala rulers as Gaudeshvara, Gaudendra, Gaudaraja etc. This obviously implies that the name Gauda, which originally denoted parts of West Bengal, became so diffused that during the 8th and 9th centuries it was sometimes synonymous with the entire Pala kingdom.
We come across the term Pancha Gauda for the first time in the famous historical chronicle of Kashmir, the Rajatarangini of Kalhana. This indicates the widest diffusion of the name Gauda. Pancha Gauda referred to Gauda in association with Sarasvata, Kanyakubja, Mithila, and Utkala. 

It thus appears that originally Gauda janapada lay to the west of Bhagirathi and that its core area was Murshidabad. Gradually, with the increase of the political might of Shashanka, the first independent ruler of Gauda, in the early part of 7th century AD, the political limits of Gauda extended stretching in the south to coastal Orissa and the north to Pundravardhana. The term sometimes even denotes the entire Pala empire. In the 13th century gaur under the Bengal Sultans denoted the entire area of the sultanate. Its capital, also called Gaur, stood at the site previously known as Laksmanavati, and renamed LAKHNAUTI by the Muslim sultans.

Sepoy Revolt-1857


Started at Barrackpur under the leadership of Mangal Pandey on 29 March 1857 and soon spread to Meerut, Delhi and other parts of India. It created serious tension throughout Bangladesh. The resistance in Chittagong and Dhaka and skirmishes at Sylhet, Jessore, Rangpur, Pabna and Dinajpur had left Bangladesh in a state of alert and excitement. On 18 November 1857 the Native Infantry of Chittagong rose in open rebellion and released all prisoners from the jail. They seized arms and ammunition, ransacked the treasury, set the Magazine House on fire and preceded towards Tippera.
The offensive of the sepoys of Chittagong had an important bearing upon the company's defensive posture at Dhaka. Being apprehensive of a further uprising of the sepoys, the authorities sent three companies of the 54th Regiment and one hundred seamen to Dhaka. Simultaneously a Naval Brigade was sent to Jessore, Rangpur, Dinajpur and some other districts of Bangladesh. Organised local volunteers consisting mostly of European residents took special measures for the protection of Dhaka. The situation became tense when the Naval Brigade arrived at Dhaka to disarm the sepoys stationed there. On 22 November the sepoys stationed at lalbagh resisted the process of disarming. In the skirmish that followed several sepoys were killed and arrested while many of them fled towards Mymensingh. Most of the fugitives were, however, arrested and put up for summary trial by a hurriedly constituted Court Martial. Of the accused sepoys 11 were sentenced to death and the rest were sentenced to life imprisonment. The judgement was executed rather hurriedly.
Tension and excitement persisted in different parts of Bangladesh, especially in the districts of Sylhet, Mymensingh, Dinajpur and Jessore. Several skirmishes occurred between the fugitive sepoys and European soldiers in Sylhet and some other places resulting in loss of lives on both sides. Summary trials by local Judges of the captured and disarmed sepoys took place in Sylhet and Jessore. Hanging and deportation were common features of these summary trials.
The role and reaction of various classes of people of Bangladesh during the sepoy revolt present a gloomy picture. The landed aristocracy was decidedly opposed to the sepoys and some of them rendered logistic support to the company authorities by supplying carts, carriages and elephants; informing the movements of the fleeing sepoys and finally organising local volunteer corps to resist the sepoys. The government acknowledged such services of the landed aristocracy with thanks and subsequently awarded them titles of Nawab, Khan Bahadur, Khan Shaheb, Rai Bahadur, Rai Shaheb etc and rewarded them with all sorts of worldly gains. Following the role displayed by the landed aristocracy, the middle class too sided with the company's government. The common people and the peasantry as a whole were apathetic and remained untouched by the sepoy revolt, though they suffered much from the concomitant artificial price hike.